Introduction
The Minister of Finance, the
Honourable Malusi Gigaba, delivered his Medium-Term Budget Policy Statement
(MTBPS) on Wednesday, 25 October 2017. This document seeks to provide a broad
analysis of the MTBPS as presented and to highlight some shortcomings and areas
that require urgent attention if the current low growth trajectory is to be
addressed.
In particular, I intend to focus on
the following issues:
·
Monetary policy
·
Benefits of a Government Digital Strategy
·
Budgetary Allocations
Monetary Policy
Minister Gigaba, like previous
minister of Finance, devotes passing remarks in various places to monetary
policy, and yet this is the most potent policy instrument available to the
government and the South African Reserve Bank (SARB) to influence the growth
rate and reduce unemployment. The apparent failure to realise that it is the
contractionary policies of the SARB that are negatively impacting growth and
employment is puzzling as there’s ample theoretical and empirical evidence to
suggest this. In several places, the minister remarks and observes, without any
irony, that the world economy is growing. In particular, South Africa’s major
trading partners are experiencing higher economic growth. This, as I will show
below, is happening precisely because they harnessed the power of their
monetary policies to make it happen.
Typically, the objectives of
macroeconomic policy are the attainment of full employment (or the reduction of
unemployment levels), within an environment of low inflation, high and
sustained economic growth, and a ‘healthy’ balance of payments. The emphasis on
one or the other objective is a choice that is informed by a number of factors.
Some of these may be informed by ideology, others may be the result of
pressures external to the economy (especially for a relatively small, open
economy like South Africa which is dependent on external financial flows and
trade).
All things being equal, some of
these objectives (at least in the short to medium term) may be mutually
exclusive. For instance, a low inflation (not factoring in inflationary
expectations), high interest rate environment may negatively impact economic
growth and employment levels. The opposite may also hold true. As economics is
about choice, policy makers make choices that ultimately harm or benefit their
economies and citizens.
There’s general consensus (and
empirical evidence clearly upholds this) about the inverse relationship between
the level of interest rates and the rate of economic growth and the level of
employment. Put simply, high interest rates lead to lower levels of economic
growth and therefore lower levels of employment (or higher unemployment). High
interest rates may attract speculative international financial flows, but these
are generally fleeting and mostly do not lead to productive investments. On the
other hand, they negatively impact demand and domestic investment expenditure.
All things being equal, the current
inflation target (range), with the resultant relatively high interest
environment, is incompatible with the stated growth and employment objectives.
In other words, the current monetary policy stance of the SARB harms the
country’s growth prospects and is not supportive of the government’s stated
growth and employment objectives.
The minister and the SARB should
dispassionately and non-ideologically take stock of the situation and accept,
as evidence seems to suggest, that they will not attain their growth and
employment targets with the current policy incompatibility. Since the mandate
of the SARB comes from government, more specifically the minister of Finance,
it is inconsistent to persist with an inflation target range that clearly is at
odds with the growth target and the creation of employment. What compounds the
situation is the observed, unstated goal of the SARB to target the median of
the range. What is the point of the 6% upper limit if the SARB conducts policy
in such a way that the rate of inflation is generally restricted from testing
this upper limit?
Although the minister observes that
high unemployment remains one of South Africa’s most pressing challenges, he
offers nothing radical or creative to deal with this. The reduction of unemployment, and not a low rate of inflation,
should be the key objective of macroeconomic policy in the short to medium
term. This would have a positive impact on the budget deficit through reduced
social spending while revenue collections increase. This would allow the
government space to increase spending on growth enhancing items like education,
even as the number of those who cannot afford fees reduces (or they require a
lower ‘subsidy’). In other words, creating a ‘virtuous circle.’
Clearly, this monetary policy would
have to be complemented by strategies implemented by government and the private
sector to ensure that growth is in sectors with the greatest employment
creation potential. In other words, avoid the curse of jobless growth.
It is interesting to note that the
wage increases typically demanded by unions, particularly public-sector unions,
clearly indicate that their inflationary expectations are consistently higher
than CPI. This is puzzling as the SARB has maintained consistently low and
relatively stable rates for a long time. This, in fact, seems to reflect the
strong power that unions have in South Africa. This may reflect general
historical union development, but it may also be due to the existence of an
alliance between unions and the governing party.
Aggressive Monetary Policy – the US, UK, EU, Japan and China
Central banks ordinarily conduct
monetary policy by buying and selling short-term debt securities to target
short-term nominal interest rates. These purchases and sales of assets change
both short-term interest rates and the monetary base (the quantity of currency
and bank reserves in the economy.) This conventional monetary policy can
potentially stimulate the economy through two types of channels: asset price
channels (including interest rates) and credit channels.
However, when interest rates are at
zero increasing the monetary base is not, by itself, considered an effective
stimulus. This is what the central banks of the United States, the United
Kingdom, the European Union and Japan were faced with when they lowered their
rates to zero to alleviate financial distress and stimulate their economies.
Faced with this scenario, the Fed,
the Bank of England (BOE), the European Central Bank (ECB) and the Bank of
Japan (BOJ) turned to unconventional policies that often dramatically increase
their monetary bases. Some of these unconventional policies involve direct
lending to specific distressed short-term credit markets, whereas others
involve purchasing long-term assets that are intended to reduce real, long-term
interest rates.
The Fed, BOE and ECB have steered
their respective economies through these difficult times and further showed
that their decision-making is empirically based. For example, in recent times whenever
there has been an expectation that the Fed will raise interest rates, it has
not done so because the employment numbers have indicated to them that the US
economy is still fragile.
The People’s Bank of China (PBOC)
has shown similar responsiveness to shocks to the Chinese economy, for instance
when there was a stock market collapse and the slowing down of the economy.
The purpose of this section has
been to show that other central banks have been prepared to lower interest
rates to zero and then to further
implement unconventional policies in
order to stimulate economic growth. (Employment growth acts as an excellent
proxy for this as it is among the first indicators of improving business
confidence.) This happened in an environment of scepticism about the potential
effectiveness of these policies, but they stayed the course and the evidence
suggests they were correct. Interestingly, with the exception of the PBOC, these
are central banks in ‘right wing’ economies, while the SARB and Treasury in a
‘left wing’ environment are steadfastly implementing policies that are
anti-growth and anti-employment.
Benefits of a Government Digital Strategy
Want to reduce corruption, reduce
the cost of doing business and serving citizens? Studies show that digitization
is one of the biggest drivers of a nation’s economic success. Digitization
reduces the costs of doing business for both the state and private economic
actors, in turn benefiting the economy as a whole. Digitisation also markedly reduces
the incidence of corruption and increases access for citizens to services at
reduced cost.
For example, digitizing procurement
increases competition, reduces costs, reduces arbitrary decision-making,
reduces human interaction in the submission and evaluation of tenders, thereby
eliminating or reducing opportunities for corrupt or collusive behaviour.
Downloadable tender documents and digital submission also benefit the
environment in many ways: it reduces the need for printing and for driving to
collect and submit documents, etc.
In another example, a pilot study
in the US involved the use of Artificial Intelligence/algorithms to allocate
bail for various categories of offences. This showed a marked reduction in the
prison population of awaiting trial prisoners. This clearly has budgetary and
justice benefits.
With no bias in decision-making,
algorithms can take over a lot of decision-making, especially those decisions
dependent on quantitative data. For instance, decisions about the repo rate by
the SARB can be made by algorithms without any political or other bias, purely
on the numbers. Incorporating machine learning means computers can also make
increasingly better decisions even where qualitative data are necessary for
decision-making.
The use of digital technology in
education and health care are well documented. All that is required is a clear
strategy and improved implementation efforts. Building computer labs in
township and rural schools, and then leaving these to be completely vandalised
or at the mercy of corrupt teachers is pointless and a waste of public and
donor funds. We have also seen the impact of digital technology on access to
financial services for unbanked or underbanked people.
At the other end of the scale,
access to government services may be greatly improved through improved ICT
infrastructure across the country, including poor areas and rural areas. This
should be complemented by a continued reduction in data charges.
Investment in digital services can
prove comparatively inexpensive because once the systems are in place, the
marginal cost of adding users are close to zero. For example, when you have a
computer in each village (a “digital centre”) with the birth certificate
program installed, extra birth certificates cost almost zero. And adding more
apps to the computer, allowing for help with other government services (like
agricultural extension services) adds little cost too.
Budgetary allocations
Budgetary allocations towards
social grants and housing are indeed necessary and commendable; they, however,
do not contribute to long-term economic growth. Funding allocations should
instead be focused on growth supporting activities like education and crime
fighting. An educated workforce improves business confidence and encourages
investment by business and attracts FDI. Equally, with education and better earnings
people can potentially provide housing for themselves, leaving the state to
provide only for the truly indigent. A lowering of the crime rate will also
have similar growth benefits, while also directly impacting the quality of life
of citizens.
Disposing of government’s stake in
companies like Telkom is good, but using these proceeds to recapitalise SAA is
a complete waste. There is no clear developmental justification for holding
onto a 100% stake at SAA and making budgetary allocations to it and/or
providing guarantees on its behalf. The minister’s subsequent public
justification in an interview, namely that this is to preserve jobs, is at
best, ‘throwing good money after bad’. And, at worst, it appears to be very
unscientific. Where is the research that informed this view?
‘Radical economic transformation’
should include radically reviewing the government’s ownership of SOE’s,
especially those that have no clear developmental role, and yet keep enjoying
bailouts or guarantees out of public funds.
Increasing spending on defence is
also the wrong option. South Africa is at peace with the world and will
continue to be for the foreseeable future. Why, therefore, should defence
spending increase, especially to finance expensive and fancy equipment like the
Gripen fighter jets? To fight against Swaziland or Malawi? Our porous borders,
evidenced by the millions of undocumented immigrants, also belie the
justification of border control. Maritime patrols to protect our fisheries and
a level of peace-keeping on the continent are seemingly the only justified
defence expenditure. On the other hand, drastically increasing expenditure on
the police would yield significant benefits and would in the end pay for itself
through increased FDI, tourism and other virtuous benefits as mentioned above.
Public sector salary and wage increases
The minister expresses a concern
about the possibility of public service wage negotiations concluding on an increase
that is higher than CPI. This is, at best very curious, and at worst shocking.
It is in fact not the first time that a minister of finance has raised such
concerns, but clearly seemed impotent to do anything about it. It clearly
reflects what I raised above, the power of unions to extract increases from the
government which have no basis in economic reality.
No comments:
Post a Comment